Wage falls in the UK as ordinary workers suffer since the recession

workersEvidence here, once more from the UK’s TUC (Trades Union Congress) that real wages here fell by 10.4% between 2007 and 2015; in other words, since the financial crisis and recession. This is the worst record in the group of rich OECD countries and roughly the same as Greece.

On the bright side, employment growth has been relatively strong in recent years, although putting the two together suggests that a large proportion of the jobs created pay low wages. This means that job creation is less likely to reduce poverty for those already struggling.

As I have written previously, strong population growth has flattered the GDP growth figures so that per capita growth in incomes and output has been poor since the recession.

Stagnant or falling wages should boost the profits of firms, at least for a while, which could feed through into rising investment, which is necessary for productivity growth. But if real wages do not at some point pick up, then the only way that consumption can grow is for people to take on more debt, which will eventually prove unsustainable, especially from today’s already high levels.

Of course, the government will put a positive spin on the figures by distracting from them with the employment figures and overall GDP growth rather than the per capita evidence. But the picture is clear. We have a lot of ground to make up on productivity and real wages compared with our fellow OECD members and it is these variables which play a big role in determining living standards.

The continued failure of the government’s ‘long term economic plan’

Chancellor+Exchequer+George+Osborne+Visits+w174_RpYt97l

The ex-chancellor George Osborne in his hard hat

Some evidence here that the outcomes of the oft-mentioned ‘long term economic plan’ of the UK government have fallen far short of predictions and claims. First of all: austerity. Geoff Tily, Senior Economist at the TUC, shows that public sector net borrowing for the first quarter of this financial year was £26.6bn, more than the November 2011 official forecast for the whole of the 2015/16, which was £24bn.

The cuts to public spending and tax increases have reduced the deficit much more slowly than hoped, since growth has been much weaker than forecast since 2010.

The government has claimed many times that it has turned the economy around and saved it from ruin. What it doesn’t mention is that recovery was underway when it came into office in 2010. The combination of austerity and the Eurozone crisis slowed growth significantly until 2013, when it picked up and the chancellor George Osborne in fact relaxed austerity to some extent.

The UK’s recovery since the recession has been the weakest since records began. Continue reading

Anwar Shaikh’s Classical theory of inflation

9780199390632Economic theory needs to account for the phenomenon of inflation. This post draws on Chapter 15 in Professor Anwar Shaikh’s recently published book Capitalism in which he outlines his theory of inflation under modern fiat money (state-backed money not fixed in value to gold or another commodity). He contrasts it with neoclassical and Keynesian theories, and provides empirical evidence to support his ideas.

The essence of Shaikh’s model is quite simple. Inflation, a rise in the overall price level in an economy, is determined by aggregate demand and supply, and these are influenced by three factors having either a positive or a negative effect on it: new purchasing power (PP), net profitability (the rate of profit minus the interest rate, rr) and the so-called ‘growth utilization rate’ (u).

PP is a demand-side factor, and the other two factors operate on the supply-side. PP is influenced by private and public sector credit, or a rise in borrowing to fuel greater spending in an economy. Note that this can be generated domestically or from abroad, for example through a rise in net exports. In theory, under modern fiat money, the amount of PP generated by the government ‘printing money’ has no limit, and history shows that in wartime, governments have often financed the extra demands on their activities through the creation of new money, which has given rise to inflation. This source of inflation, generated from the demand-side, seems similar to monetarist theory, in which the state is to blame via its intervention in the economy and its creation of an excessive growth of the money supply, and trying to keep unemployment below its ‘natural rate’. Continue reading

Postcapitalism: Paul Mason’s ‘guide to our future’?

MasonCoverI said I would post something on Paul Mason’s thought-provoking book, Postcapitalism – a guide to our future, which has just come out in paperback. It makes a good read, and contains a wealth of ideas from economics, political economy, and futurism, all mixed together in the author’s aim to inspire a progressive transition beyond capitalism, but not to socialism, which he admits has been a huge failure for the left. Instead, he calls his utopian vision ‘postcapitalism’.

Mason starts by describing the current political economic paradigm, neo-liberalism, as having reached its limits with the crisis of 2008 and the subsequent tepid, or in many cases absent, recovery. There has been sluggish output and productivity growth, alongside wage rises for those at the very top of the income distribution but barely any change for the middle and bottom. In fact, these trends were only temporarily overcome by the excessive expansion of credit prior to the crisis which allowed consumption to grow in countries such as the US and UK despite stagnant wages. Continue reading

The IMF changes its tune on neoliberalism (a little)

International_Monetary_Fund_logo.svgHere is a link to a recent article by IMF researchers which backtracks on some of the tenets of that institution’s policy during what could be called the neoliberal era. It makes for interesting reading.

In particular, they make the case for capital controls to stabilize financial flows in certain circumstances; for reductions in inequality through ‘predistribution’ or redistribution in order to promote more sustainable economic growth; and they cast doubt on the wisdom of austerity which aims to reduce public debt as a share of GDP through tax rises and spending reductions instead of simply through policies to promote growth.

The piece does not wholeheartedly reject neoliberalism. In fact the authors praise certain aspects of it, such as the role of the expansion of international trade in reducing poverty. But this seems like a small step in the right direction.

Optimal investment and growth: why institutions matter

CentralKigaliHow much investment is optimal for sustained economic growth? Two recent blog posts present contrasting views on the answer to this question. The first, from Michael Burke on the Socialist Economic Bulletin, puts forward a simple theory: the greater the share of investment in GDP, the faster is economic growth, within certain limits. Furthermore, he argues that widespread economic stagnation in the growth of output and productivity among the richest countries today can be remedied by a large increase in public investment. In other words, the state can lead a recovery.

The second, by Michael Pettis on his blog China Financial Markets, discusses the role of what he calls ‘social capital’, or economic, social and political institutions in a broad sense. For Pettis, it is not enough for governments to enact policies which raise the investment share in output, if the institutional framework leads to it not being utilized effectively. If there is a high level of social capital, which might include levels of education, government competence, a lack of corruption, law and order, property rights etc, then policies which increase investment should have a better chance of increasing productivity and output. If these institutions are lacking, then more investment is not enough, and it will be used unproductively. Continue reading

Marx’s Grundrisse: some key points

Karl_Marx_001

Karl Marx

Karl Marx’s Grundrisse is a collection of preparatory notebooks, laying out some of the themes which he was to explore in his great work Capital. It is not an easy read, but it helped that I have read some Marxist economics already, including Capital. Many of the ideas were therefore familiar.

Here are a few of the ideas which Marx explores in this book, with occasional comments from me: Continue reading